Home 禄 Opinion 禄 Foreign Views
Time for the Fed to learn from past mistakes
WITH interest rates near zero, the US Federal Reserve and other central banks are struggling to remain relevant.
The last arrow in their quiver is called quantitative easing (QE), and it is likely to be almost as ineffective in reviving the US economy as anything else the Fed has tried in recent years.
Worse, QE is likely to cost taxpayers a bundle, while impairing the Fed's effectiveness for years to come.
John Maynard Keynes argued that monetary policy was ineffective during the Great Depression. Central banks are better at restraining markets' irrational exuberance in a bubble - restricting the availability of credit or raising interest rates to rein in the economy - than at promoting investment in a recession. That is why good monetary policy aims to prevent bubbles from arising.
But the Fed, captured for more than two decades by market fundamentalists and Wall Street interests, not only failed to impose restraints, but acted as cheerleaders. And, having played a central role in creating the current mess, it is now trying to regain face.
In 2001, lowering interest rates seemed to work, but not the way it was supposed to. Rather than spurring investment in plant and equipment, low interest rates inflated a real-estate bubble.
This enabled a consumption binge, which meant that debt was created without a corresponding asset, and encouraged excessive investment in real estate, resulting in excess capacity that will take years to eliminate.
The best that can be said for monetary policy over the last few years is that it prevented the direst outcomes that could have followed Lehman Brothers' collapse. But no one would claim that lowering short-term interest rates spurred investment. Indeed, business lending - particularly to small businesses - in both the US and Europe remains markedly below pre-crisis levels. The Fed and the European Central Bank have done nothing about this.
They still seem enamored of the standard monetary-policy models, in which all central banks have to do to get the economy going is reduce interest rates.
Bad ideas
The standard models failed to predict the crisis, but bad ideas die a slow death. So, while bringing down short-term T-bill rates to near zero has failed, the hope is that bringing down longer-term interest rates will spur the economy. The chances of success are near zero.
Large firms are awash with cash, and lowering interest rates slightly won't make much difference to them. And lowering the rates that government pays has not translated into correspondingly lower interest rates for the many small firms struggling for financing.
More relevant is the availability of loans. With so many banks in the US fragile, lending is likely to remain constrained. Moreover, most small-business loans are collateral-based, but the value of the most common form of collateral, real estate, has plummeted.
The Obama administration's efforts to deal with the real-estate market have been a dismal failure, perhaps succeeding only in postponing further declines.
But even optimists don't believe that real-estate prices will increase substantially any time soon. In short, QE - lowering long-term interest rates by buying long-term bonds and mortgages - won't do much to stimulate business directly.
It may help, though, in two ways. One way is as part of America's strategy of competitive devaluation.
Officially, America still talks about the virtues of a strong dollar, but lowering interest rates weakens the exchange rate. Whether one views this as currency manipulation or as an accidental by-product of lower interest rates is irrelevant.
The fact is that a weaker dollar resulting from lower interest rates gives the US a slight competitive advantage in trade.
Meanwhile, as investors look outside the US for higher yield, the flood of money out of the dollar has bid up exchange rates in emerging markets around the world.
Emerging markets know this, and are upset - Brazil has vehemently expressed its concerns - not only about the increased value of their currency, but that the influx of money risks fueling asset bubbles or triggering inflation.
The normal response of emerging-market central banks to bubbles or inflation would be to raise interest rates - thereby increasing their currencies' value still more. US policy is thus delivering a double whammy on competitive devaluation - weakening the dollar and forcing competitors to strengthen their currencies (though some are taking countermeasures, erecting barriers to short-term inflows and intervening more directly in foreign-exchange markets).
The second way that QE might have a slight effect is by lowering mortgage rates, which would help to sustain real-estate prices. So QE would produce some - probably weak - balance-sheet effects.
But potentially significant costs offset these small benefits. The Fed has bought more than US$1 trillion of mortgages, the value of which will fall when the economy recovers - which is precisely why no one in the private sector wants to buy them.
New mistakes
The government may pretend that it has not experienced a capital loss, because, unlike banks, it is not required to use mark-to-market accounting.
But no one should be fooled, even if the Fed holds the bonds to maturity. The attempt to ensure that the losses are not recognized might tempt the Fed to rely excessively on untested, uncertain, and costly monetary-policy tools - like paying high interest rates on reserves to induce banks not to lend.
It is good that the Fed is trying to make amends for its dismal pre-crisis performance. Regrettably, it is far from clear that it has changed its thinking and models, which failed to maintain the economy on an even keel before - and are certain to fail again.
The Fed's previous mistakes proved extraordinarily costly. So will the new mistakes, even if the Fed strives to hide the price tag.
(The author, a Nobel laureate in economics, is University Professor of Economics at Columbia University. Copyright. Project Syndicate, 2010. www.project-syndicate.org)
- About Us
- |
- Terms of Use
- |
-
RSS
- |
- Privacy Policy
- |
- Contact Us
- |
- Shanghai Call Center: 962288
- |
- Tip-off hotline: 52920043
- 娌狪CP璇侊細娌狪CP澶05050403鍙-1
- |
- 浜掕仈缃戞柊闂讳俊鎭湇鍔¤鍙瘉锛31120180004
- |
- 缃戠粶瑙嗗惉璁稿彲璇侊細0909346
- |
- 骞挎挱鐢佃鑺傜洰鍒朵綔璁稿彲璇侊細娌瓧绗354鍙
- |
- 澧炲肩數淇′笟鍔$粡钀ヨ鍙瘉锛氭勃B2-20120012
Copyright 漏 1999- Shanghai Daily. All rights reserved.Preferably viewed with Internet Explorer 8 or newer browsers.